Extract from an Essay I wrote in Political Economy in 2012 that I put in my blog for the benefit of my friends - please note that I am not an authority, but that I read quite extensively on the subject in order to address the question put to me below
Explain
why, despite being a huge debtor economy, the US seems able to
operate in a privileged position in the world economy? Is this
sustainable?
In
1965, a while ago, Valery Giscard d’Estaing, De Gaulle’s
finance’s minister, would describe the position of US economy as
one of ‘Exorbitant privilege’. The term refers to the benefits
held by the US as a result of having the US Dollar being the
international reserve currency: the outrage was about the European
nations financing the Vietnam war whether they liked it or not,
simply because of the privilege of the US being able to print
dollars. Already then, Giscard was pointing out a major ‘anomaly’
in the world economic system. Today, L. H. Summers, a key economic
advisor in the US administration, uses the term ‘Balance of Terror’
to describe a situation when “we rely on the costs of others
(surplus economy countries like China principally) not financing our
current account deficit (US Deficit) as assurance that financing will
continue” (2004: 8). Something has gone wrong, but the USD is still
the currency of choice for world finance transactions, investments,
international trade, and foreign exchange reserves for most
countries.
Why
is it that despite running a huge debtor economy, the US economy
still occupies such a privileged position?
There
are different reasons for that. First, I will briefly look at the
historical background: the Bretton Wood II legacy and explain how as
a result of holding the world currency, the US can afford to run huge
debt with little to no ‘real cost’ of finance, without impunity,
nor ‘tears’.
I will then show how the current political climate in China also
contributes to the US being able to operate in a privileged position
in the World Economy at the moment. Finally, I will take a critical
stance on the word ‘privilege’ for the US economy and explain the
reasons why there is not a better solution at the moment.
From
Bretton Wood I to Bretton Wood II
-
The US dollar became the world currency in the aftermath of WWII, as
part of the grand post-war international monetary and financial order
endorsed by 44 countries in Bretton Woods. The idea was to avoid a
return to the previous classical liberal international economic order
that lead to the Great Depression in the pre-30s, by giving
governments the means to control speculative private investments.
Public international institutions were assigned the key role in
allocating short term and long term credit at an international level.
There was a wish to establish a world of international currencies
stability and enable domestic policy autonomy, what Ruggie (1982)
would call ‘embedded liberalism’. The dollar was linked to gold
which meant that Washington had to take action whenever trade
deficits translated into depleted gold reserves. In 1960, Robert
Triffin warned about the weakness of such a system: international
liquidity could only be expanded if the US could provide the world
with more dollars. According to Boltho, having the USD as world
currency as part of Bretton Wood I order was not a bad thing: the
world trade and growth expanded in the post war period after Bretton
Woods in the developed world and many countries in the developing
world have done extremely well thanks partly to the dollar’s
presence during the pre-70s period. America provided the liquidity
which growing world trade required (2011: 150). This is not so true
after the deregulation period that followed. As the US started to
print more dollars, soon the dollar could not be converted into gold.
A crisis of confidence followed and in 1971; the US chose to free
itself from the constraints that the gold convertibility imposed.
This was the end of the governments using economic tightening to
reverse structural trade deficits. After that, many OECD governments
dismantled capital controls with the US and UK leading the way in
1974 and 1979 respectively. This is what Murphy called: Bretton Wood
II, a new order with no formal institutional requirement for anyone
to support it, in which the US could still take advantage of holding
the world currency, despite having now the competitive advantage to
have its creditors finance the US trade deficit out of their vested
interest in the continuation of a US-led financial system (Murphy
2006: 41).
I
am now going to expose the mechanisms behind The US derives huge
privileges out of the dollar being the world currency
The
US is a debtor economy (see below chart).
In
such a case, according to market laws, a declining of its currency
over time is supposed to reduce imports and help exports, thus
reducing the deficit. Yet, the USD did not depreciate as hugely as
it should have. Why?
The
first reason the US takes advantage of its position as world currency
holder is that the US can issue dollar assets at very low rates of
interest to finance its deficits, in other words, it has access to
cheap money. Due to its role as the international reserve currency,
the demand of US assets (principally Treasury Bonds) is higher than
it should otherwise be. The dollars of surplus economies are invested
in US Treasury Bonds, but because so many surplus countries want them
as their economies expand and their central banks want to augment
their dollar reserves, the US Bonds interest rate is low and has been
going down over the last decade (Boltho 2011: 148) this
lowers the price of borrowing for the US.
The US pays less than other countries for the price of borrowing and
the US find itself in a situation of competitive borrowing advantage.
The
second advantage is that the US is the only country in the world that
does not need to fear slow depreciation of its currency ‘Since
almost all US foreign liabilities are denominated in its own currency
and about 70% of US foreign assets are in foreign currencies, a
dollar depreciation represents a net transfer of wealth from the rest
of the world’ (Lucarelli 2008: 25). A cheaper USD lowers US debt
repayments since the debt is typically denominated in USD. In other
words, dollar depreciation reduces net external debt. It is the
opposite for other countries who cannot afford to have too low
currencies as it would make their debt repayments higher.
Furthermore, a slow depreciation of the USD does not cause too much
of problem for imports as it should under normal market laws, as
long as the US has access to very cheap imports.
The
third advantage is that ‘the US acting as an international
financial intermediary enjoys higher returns on foreign investments
than foreigners earn on their respective US investments’
(Papadimitriou, et al, 2006: 4). In sharp contrast to the other
economies, the US is able to invest abroad in
its own currency.
It earns more on its investments abroad than foreigners do in the US.
This
is how the
US has been able to exploit the USD as key global currency: borrowing
short and lending long aided by the dollar’s reserve currency
status with no ties.
As a result, the difference between what the US pays and what it
earns from the rest of the world (NIIP) has not deteriorated as much
as one would expect when the US is incurring such large current
account deficits (Lucarelli 2008: 24).
The
last but not least advantage
is that the key currency role of the dollar provides the US not only
economic advantages, but consequently ‘structural power’: it
increases political influence.
The necessary money to finance military projects is created by the
Federal Reserve, in exchange for goods and services from foreigners,
and borrowed back by the US Treasury. This leads to the outrageous
situations mentioned in the introduction and restates questions such
as, should European countries have facilitated the financing of the
war in Vietnam, and China the Iraq war, without a say? Why should
surplus countries indirectly finance US military projects? The
question is all the more relevant that even if the US wishes to keep
its world currency holder status, can it be trusted that when its
interests conflict with those of the rest of the world, will it
choose unilateral action?
(The scope of this essay does not allow further development of this
point, but the question needs to be raised)
Another
main reason why the US has been able to operate in such a privileged
position in the world economy is linked to the world main economies
of US and China’s respective domestic situation.
Let’s
begin with China –
Unlike the US, China has been running gigantic surpluses in current
account (trade) and capital account (FDI),
so it should be enjoying a strong currency, access to cheaper imports
and a higher standard of living for all. This is evidently not the
case. Instead, the Chinese government has artificially contained the
Chinese currency, the RMB, and a large part of the country’s
surplus are going instead to the US in the form of US bonds
remunerated at around 0.2%
, furthering the US privileged situation.
The
Chinese government tries to artificially contain its currency for
several reasons. Firstly it aims to keep the exchange rate
competitive for exports to the US, since they consider that the
current Chinese market has not yet developed into a fully mature
consumer market. It is clear that if the PBC did not try to contain
the pressure on the value of the RMB artificially, an appreciating
currency would eventually correct the trade surplus over time.
Secondly,
the domestic monetary impact (possible inflation that Chinese
authorities fear) could lead to local unrest in an authoritarian,
highly unequal society. Thirdly it wards off any potential
speculative attacks on the currency, thereby guaranteeing a stable
competitive currency. Thus market forces are functioning
artificially.
Will
the US be able to take advantage of this access to cheap finance (US
Bonds) and cheap goods made by the Chinese rural-poor who do not see
their wages go up as they should for very long?
In
the longer term, China should be able to rely more on its domestic
consumption and/or another alternative to full-blown export-led
growth, and thereby rely less on US markets for exports. We will then
see an appreciation of the currency and less competitive exports. It
is not known when this will happen. We only know it will take time.
For now, there are still very large inequalities: Chinese households
are not big consumers – house consumption 30% of GDP in China as
opposed to 50% of GDP in US, and there is a need for more
equalisation of earnings in order to help spread consumption in the
country. Without a social security system, the Chinese poor are
forced to make savings. These savings are further exploited by very
low return, again as a direct result of policies distorting the
market laws. As a result, the Chinese peasants’ low wages and
savings are fuelling Western debt. It is not clear how sustainable
this urban bias will last without creating serious social unrest.
In
2008, when the export engine stalled, the PRC rolled out a gigantic
USD $570 fiscal-stimulus package. However no more than 20% was social
spending. The rest went into fixed-assets investments in the steel,
cement running in overcapacity, and high speed rail system
construction with uncertain prospects (Hung Ho-Fung 2009: 22). The
PRC has not yet begun to show a real willingness to promote domestic
consumption.
Until
the Chinese government stops holding the value of the RBM
artificially low, the US will access cheap credit through US Bonds
remunerated at 0.2%, financed by Chinese workers who try to save for
their pension funds.
Let’s
take a critical stance at this ‘privilege’ - what
Chinese Premier, Wen Jiabao, denounces an “unsustainable model of
development”. Is it a real privilege for the US to have access to
such cheap credit and goods?
In
the Western World Economies, as a result of the sudden massive access
to cheap credit from South East Asia (China principally), we find
ourselves in a US consumption model
which depends more on credit creation than income growth: a
non–fordist type of capitalism (Lucarelli 2008: 28)
In
the US, the rapid expansion of liquidity has created enormous wealth
but only to serve asset price inflation, namely the housing market
and speculative financial assets. We find ourselves in a capitalist
world without redistribution for labour. We are departing from real
economy to speculative economies. The average household or
retiree
is increasingly exposed to uncontrollable and increasingly more
frequent speculative assets bubbles crashes – dot.com bubble in
2000, retirement investments funds debacle in 2008 - that comes down
to affect the average household capacity to housing and pay its
grocery bill. This situation does not seem sustainable.
Emerging
markets complained that as their economies expanded, and their
central banks felt compelled to augment their dollar reserves, they
were obliged to provide cheap finance for the US external deficit,
like it or not’(Boltho 2011:146)
We
have an outrageous situation where people in China, for example, are
working in poor conditions and saving safety net money at
artificially low interest rates in order to fuel debt ridden rich
economies.
Status
Quo - Why is there no better solution at the moment?
We
can easily imagine that as US large budget deficits and public debt
are unlikely to come down soon, in the present situation, this could
lead eventually to upward pressure on domestic interest rates or lead
to higher inflation. Growth would slow down. Even that would not
create a sudden flight from the dollar as there is a lack of
sufficiently attractive alternatives. A massive selloff of US Bonds
is not much of a solution for surplus countries as they would see the
value of their holdings decline. China may sell some of its US Gvt
bonds and increase its euro and yen assets to diversify the risk.
Eichengreen foresees a world of multiple international currencies,
with the euro and the renminbi playing more significant roles at
regional levels – not unlike the 19th
century experience when the sterling’s predominance was tempered by
the presence of the franc and the mark. For now, the Euro is a
currency with not enough state (not enough fiscal or political
integration of the independent Maastricht Central Bank) and one with
a distinctly uncertain future (Boltho 2011: 147). Political
integration in Europe will follow as it always has but it will be
slow, because institutional reforms are slow.
The
Chinese renminbi is still inconvertible with too much state (China
has strict capital control, reluctant to let foreigners hold, buy and
set its assets, barely ready to give its own people financial
freedom: interest on banks deposits is capped; shares are largely
owned by state entities; and bonds are chiefly held by banks – in
turn owned by the state (Economist
2011: 12), but overtime this may change .There are talks about the
renminbi become convertible as early as 2020 (Eichengreen 2011 cited
in Boltho 2011: 147). It may be the only way forward: no one will
want to borrow in a currency that is only going to strengthen,
increasing the value of their debts. So China needs a currency that
can go up and down like the rest of the world. China will have to
loosen its currency’s peg and let it rise.
Another
concern is that the World Central banks are bound together in a
Prisoner’s dilemma situation - if a growing number of central
banks feel obliged to protect themselves against a falling US dollar
by diversifying their foreign holding, the whole system of dollar
recycling would collapse with quite devastating consequences. ‘There
is a classical dilemma akin to the prisoner’s dilemma in game
theory: all central banks would be assured stability if no single
central bank decided to diversify out of US dollar reserve assets’
(Lucarelli 2008: 20). Unfortunately, this is not stopping the problem
as the risk of a dollar crisis increases in the meanwhile.
The
best solution at hand is still the US Dollar: no country in the world
comes near the level of stability the US still offers. US Government
bonds have never defaulted in history – fixed income investment –
safe reserves for China – buffer against crisis to pay current
account deficit. They are a very liquid kind of asset, can be sold
quickly to get cash quickly. For the main US Bonds purchaser, China,
SAFETY is the first concern, LIQUIDITY the second, and PROFIT the
last. The US contemporary economy is robust: twice the size of the
combined economies of Germany, France and Britain, it has
institutional depth, vitality, and political stability and unmatched
physical security (Kirshner 2008: 419). The US military supremacy
acts as a warrant of stability and this is a vicious circle: In The
Invisible Hand of the American Empire,
Robert Wade argues that ‘the economic benefits that accrue to the
United States as the result of the normal working of market forces
within this particular framework then provide the bias of American
Military supremacy, which help to protect the framework’ (2003:
77).
Conclusion:
While
there is no formal institutional requirement to support the Bretton
Woods II order, the US is still in 2012 the world currency holder. We
have seen the exorbitant privileges the US derives from this
position. I have described how the US current deficit feeds on the
developing world foreign exchange reserve assets. The two major
players in the world economy, the US and China, are currently
paralysed in a deadly embrace. This essay does not question the
economic liberal model but instead points out to the extreme trade
and finances deregularisation movement that started in the 70s, which
went as far as compromising independent finance safety mechanisms
that led to world a number of large scale financial crisis. Likewise,
I showed how, despite some cautious attempts, the market laws have
not been able to function properly at all in China and that it may be
too late to reverse this trend. The two major players’ economies’
respective local political situation does not allow them to make the
necessary moves towards sound economic practices. While it does not
seem right that the developing world economies should provide cheap
money out of hard won savings they ‘have to build’ as a social
safety net, or against foreign speculative attacks, the lack of
alternative sustains the status quo. The question is for how long?